Time Pollution
by John Whitelegg
Although time-savings provide the principal economic
justification for new road schemes, the expansion of the road
network and the increase in traffic does not seem to have given people more
free time. This is because pedestrian time is not evaluated, because cars are
deceptively time-consuming, and because people tend to use what time
savings they do gain to travel further.
Time is money, we are told; and increasing mobility is a way of saving time. But how successful are modern transport systems at saving time?
Michael
Ende's novel Momo1 describes the changes which took
place in the daily lives of a small community when ”time thieves” persuaded the
residents to save time rather than ”waste” it on idle conversation, caring for
the elderly and similar social activities. The effects were dramatic: as the
traditional café was converted into a fast-food outlet and other changes
took place, people were too busy saving time to find any time for each other.
The village barber found that:
”he was becoming increasingly
restless and irritable. The odd thing was that, no matter how much time he
saved, he never had any to spare; in some mysterious way, it simply
vanished. Imperceptibly at first, but then quite unmistakably, his days grew
shorter and shorter. Almost before he knew it, another week had gone by,
another month, and another year, and another and another.”
Ende’s
novel compresses into a few months the process of community disintegration that
has been taking place over the last few decades in Europe. The observation that
”no one has any time for each other any more” is a commonplace, particularly
among older people; yet there are few attempts to examine why this should be
so. How can we explain the Momo effect, the paradox that the more people try to
save time, the less they seem to have? In other words, what do people do with
the time they save?
More
Speed, Less Access
The
work of Torsten Hagerstrand over the last 30 years is an important but neglected
contribution to the understanding of people's use of space and time.2
He suggests that the ability to make contact with places and other people is
the central organising feature of human activity and that it is ease of access
to other people and facilities that determines the success of a transportation
system, rather than the means or the speed of transport.
It is
relatively easy to increase the speed at which people move around, much harder
to introduce changes that enable us to spend less time gaining access to the
facilities that we need.
On this
important matter there are very few indicators which can reveal how well our
transportation systems are performing in the 1990s, by comparison (for example)
with the 1920s. What is without doubt is that facilities are sited further
apart and that people have to travel further than they did 70 years ago to
reach them. In their home territories, they must travel further to supermarkets
or leisure facilities and often must cover some distance while looking for
somewhere to park. In their work, they must be prepared to commute further
afield to find jobs. In their leisure time people contemplate day trips to
Brussels, Paris or Stockholm when previously they would have thought the idea
ridiculous.
C. Marchetti has
shown that the amount of time each person devotes to travel is roughly the same
regardless of how fast or how far they travel. ”When people gain speed they use
it to travel further and not to make more trips. In other words most
individuals treat their territory the same way whatever size it is.”3
Those who use technology to travel at greater speeds still have to make the
same amount of contacts—still work, eat, sleep and play in the same
proportions as always. They simply do these things further apart from each
other.
Do they
do so by choice or through obligation? A circular logic operates here. While
the distances between hospitals, schools, shopping centres and the like have
risen, nothing can be done to increase the number of hours in the day. Speed
must therefore be increased, and investments are made in quicker forms of
transport—families buy faster cars, governments build faster roads and
railways. But the time savings promised by new motorways and high-speed trains
appear to release time for more travel and thus spur the consumption of distance
to ever higher levels of achievement. When people save time, they use it to
buy more distance.
Social
Speeds
The
suggestion that people spend about the same amount of time travelling, whatever
their mode of transport, does not, however, explain the Momo effect: many people
feel they have less time than they had before, despite faster means of
transport.
There
is another hidden time factor in the equation. Motor cars and other high speed
vehicles do not save as much time as they appear to, as Ivan Illich pointed out
in 1974:
”The typical
American male devotes more than 1,600 hours a year to his car. He sits in it
while it goes and while it stands idling. He parks and searches for it. He
earns the money to put down on it and to meet the monthly instalments. He
works to pay for petrol, tolls, insurance taxes and tickets.”
Elaborating
on Illich’s observations, D. Seifried5 has coined the term ”social
speed” to signify the average speed of a vehicle, once a number of these hidden
factors have been taken into account (see Table 1). According to Seifried, the
social speed of a typical bicycle is 14 kilometres per hour (kph), only three
kph slower than that of a small car. If other external costs (air and noise
pollution, accident costs, road construction costs and so on) are taken into
account as well, then the small car is one kph slower than the bicycle.
Thus
the owner of a small car who spends 30 minutes per day driving 20 kilometres
may feel that she is travelling faster than a bicyclist who spends the same
time covering seven-and a half kilometres. But when the social speed is taken
into account, it emerges that the car owner is likely to be spending 70 minutes
per day while the bicyclist is spending only 32. Ecce Momo!
Space
Pollution
Whereas
speed consumes distance, a mode of transport occupies space—and the faster the
mode of transport the more space it requires. According to a 1985 Swiss study,6
a car travelling at 40 kph requires over three times as much as space as a car
travelling at 10 kph (see Table 2). Furthermore the ”bodywork” often
associated with high-speed vehicles demands space even when the vehicle is
travelling slowly: a single person in a car travelling at 10 kph requires six
times as much space as a person riding a bicycle at the same speed.
Space
therefore has to be consumed in large quantities to provide the infrastructure
for high-speed travel, as can be witnessed in the land requirements for new
motorways, high-speed rail routes and airports. Roads designed to carry traffic
at speeds over 120 kph take up more land than roads designed for lower speeds,
and the same is true for high-speed rail—fast cars and trains cannot take tight
bends. Urban motorway and ”relief” road construction is the ultimate
expression of space sacrificed for speed.
When
the demand for space is not met at certain points in the network, the result is
congestion—the familiar situation where cars costing up to £20,000 and
designed to travel at 175 kph cannot average speeds much above 20 kph. The
current enthusiasm for charging motorists for their use of road space through
toll roads and electronic road pricing arises out of a hope that it will ease
congestion. Traffic flow on these roads can be regulated by adjusting the level
of the toll. This will save time for one group (wealthy motorists) at the
expense of other groups (such as poor car-owners or pedestrians) and at the
expense of greater levels of space inefficiency. Table 2 shows that in terms of
space efficiency, the car is extremely wasteful. Paying for that space does not
alter this equation.
Time Thieves
As higher speeds
lead to greater distances between facilities, people overcome this distance either
by allocating more time to travel or by gaining access to modes of transport
with higher speeds. The result of both has been an accentuation of social
differences. While those with access to high-performance cars and regular
transcontinental air flights have seen their radius of activity expand
immeasurably over the last few decades, that of an unemployed black resident of
London or an elderly person in Montgomery, Alabama, for instance, may be no
greater than that of an urban resident 100 years ago. The poor and unemployed,
whose time is valued very low, are expected to find the time to devote to
travel; the rich have the money to buy travel and more likely to do so because
their time is considered more valuable. The more emphasis put on time savings,
the more the whole transport system becomes skewed to serve a wealthy
élite.
Transport policies
and policies which influence location and accessibility of basic facilities
steal time from different groups in society and reallocate it to (usually)
richer groups. The relocation of shops, hospitals and schools at a greater
distance from the community that needs them imposes serious time penalties on
other users. Those without cars (still about 35 per cent of the U.K.
population), and those without access to them during the day, must spend more
time searching for other facilities, waiting for buses, waiting for friends to
give them lifts, or walking. Among the groups particularly affected in a male-
and car-dominated planning system are women, children, the elderly and the
infirm. For women travelling alone after dark, there are potentially serious
consequences arising from waiting at bus stops or for late trains or for using
another device designed to maximise vehicle convenience at the expense of
pedestrians: the underpass. Women are more likely to be bus users than men,
more likely to be in charge of young children in dangerous pedestrian
environments and more likely to be involved with escorting duties arising from
the unacceptability of letting children walk unsupervised in environments
rendered lethal by traffic. In Britain, women spend many thousands of hours
escorting children in an environment rendered unsafe for children, mainly by
men. Using Department of Transport (DOT) methods of valuation, the cost of this
escorting has been estimated at over £10 billion.7 If this
cost had been taken into account, the planning process would have produced a
different outcome.
The Price of Time
The provision of high-quality urban roads, large car parks and (soon)
in-car navigation is dependent upon a high valuation of the time of the car
occupant. Road schemes in Britain are justified by assigning a monetary value
to the time they will save for motorists. The author of one study8
describes an urban road construction and improvement scheme in Leicester where
time savings made up 96.4 per cent of the gross benefits in the DOT’s
cost-benefit evaluation (COBA). The average time savings over several projects
was 90 per cent of the value of the benefits. Where the proposed road might
block pedestrian movements or require an increase in the time devoted to escorting
children, this was not offset against the time gained. Nor was attention given
to the question of how this newly won time might be reallocated in an economically
productive way to justify the assignment of monetary values.
The Leicester study also revealed that most of these predicted time
savings for motorists were very small, in the order of five minutes or less. It
calculated that when the value given by COBA to each time-saving of less than
three minutes was reduced by 75 per cent, the estimated first-year rate of
return of the scheme fell from 20 per cent to five per cent—a rate of return
that would cast severe doubts upon the financial viability of the project. Time
savings of three minutes are likely to fall within the routine variability of
any journey and cannot be easily be reallocated to ”useful” time. Furthermore,
in any road scheme there will be innumerable other repercussions which take up
three minutes—the time taken by pedestrians to make a detour through an underpass,
for example. The monetarisation of motorists’ time savings is a convenient
fiction that enables the evaluation process to come up with the desired
answer—build the road.
If putting high values on the time of drivers, even down to very short
periods, leads to more road building, putting a high value on the time of
cyclists and pedestrians would restructure present transport systems. Traffic
would have to give way to pedestrians so as not to delay them, purpose-built
pedestrian and cycle facilities would win new investment, and proposals that
encouraged pedestrians to linger and make use of space whilst slowing down
traffic would gain precedence. This is encouraging a ”waste of time” and might
be seen to imply that motorists’ time-savings is no less ridiculous than
current practices and would encourage cities and villages to develop as social,
productive, enjoyable and secure places.
Jane Jacobs’
account of city life in the U.S. some 30 years ago9 shows how
important ordinary but diverse contact is to people’s well-being. Maintaining a
sense of community needs an investment of time and energy in contact with
neighbours and local groups. The opportunities for such contact depend on time
available and thus on priorities. The decision to travel longer distances (and
save time at higher speeds) means that little time is available for interaction
with neighbours, and so there is less chance of a genuine community developing
or maintaining itself.
Motorists not only
restrict their own lives in this respect, but also those of other people.
Detailed studies on the effect of traffic volumes upon different street
communities in San Francisco10 showed, unsurprisingly, that streets
with heavy traffic have relatively little social interaction; residents of
streets with light traffic had three times as many local friends and
acquaintances as did residents of busy streets.
Time is central to
notions of sustainability. A sustainable city or a sustainable transport policy
or a sustainable economy cannot be founded on economic principles which,
through their monetarisation of time, orientate society towards higher levels
of motorisation, faster speeds and greater consumption of space. The fact that
these characteristics produce energy-intensive societies and pollution is only
part of the problem. They also distort value systems, elevate mobility above
accessibility, associate higher speeds and greater distances with progress, and
dislocate communities and social life.
Sustainability involves significant changes in the way markets operate and the ways individuals behave. Time valuation is one area ripe for change. Current methods of valuation provide an economic rationale for more travel and more pollution and justify the poor conditions for cyclists and pedestrians. They also explain why solutions such as catalytic converters and road-pricing and even improved public transport are irrelevant. None of these agents in themselves will alter the economic trajectory that is now in place.
This article, which
appeared in The Ecologist (Vol. 23, No. 4, July/August 1993) is a
shortened and adapted version of Chapter V of Transport for a
Sustainable Future: The Case for Europe, by John Whitelegg, published by
Belhaven Press, London. 1993. Dr. John Whitelegg is Head of the
Geography Department at Lancaster University and an international transport and
environment consultant.
References
1. Ende, M.,
Momo, Penguin, London, 1984.
2. Hagerstrand, T.,
”Space, Time and the Human Condition”, in Kariquist, A., Lundquist, L. and
Snickars, F., (eds.) Dynamic Allocation of Urban Space,
Saxon House, Lexington, M., 1975.
3. Marchetti, C., Building
Bridges and Tunnels: the Effect on the Evolution of Traffic, Document
SR-88-01, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Vienna, 1981.
4. Illich, I.,
Energy and Equity, Marion Boyars, London, 1974.
5. Seifried, D., Gute
Argumente: Verkchr, Beck'sche Reihe, Beck, Munich, 1990.
6. Navarro, R.A.,
Heierli, U. and Beck, V., Alternativas de Transporte en America
Latina: la Bicicleta y los Triciclos, SKAT, Centro Suizo de
Technologia Apropiada, St Gallen, Switzerland, 1985.
7. Hillman, H.,
Adams, J., and Whitelegg, J., One False Move: a Study of
Children’s Independent
Mobility, Policy Study
Institute, London, 1990.
8. Sharp, C.H., Transport
Economics, Macmillan, London,1973.
9. Jacobs, J., The
Death and Life of American Cities, Pelican, London, 1961.
10. Appleyard, D.,
Livable Streets, University of California, Berkeley, 1981.